2002
MLA
Globalization and the Image II: The Global Image
Cornelius
Conover
Univ. of Texas at Austin
The
Imaginary Peso:
Imagistic Strategies of Nineteenth-Century Mexican Coins
Do not cite without permission of the author.
Cada país
tiene su moneda, como cada país tiene su idioma; y del mismo modo
que la historia de éste es la base de su filología nacional,
la historia de aquella caracterizada distingue sus principales rasgos
fisonómicos.
Santiago Ramirez IV.
Footless
they climb step handless they travel, wandering from hand to hand. Speechless
they give testimony of the sovereign's overwhelming power, untaught they
tell of his superior might.
Ali. (qtd. in Kafadar 86).
The use of
money expanded with the development of capitalism and the rise of the
state. Money became integrated into society, which endowed it with significance,
defined its appropriate spheres and created accompanying ritual. The first
coins provided a standard unit of exchange for merchants and consumers.
Coins also provided a means for the government to collect taxes and tribute
in a more liquid form than grain or labor. Political leaders exercised
control over the currency circulating in its realm by defining what money
was valid for government transactions. Thus, coins became part of the
political project communicating to even an illiterate audience. Political
leaders chose their symbols based on locally-resonant images of power
and legitimacy. These images, symbols and words represented a historically-generated
cultural text, but also a cultural script informing subjects, citizens,
enemies and innocent bystanders of the state's sovereignty.
However, these coins soon escaped the political borders where they were
created. From the beginning of their use, trade spread coins along the
path of human economic relationships. By the nineteenth century there
was a quantitative and qualitative intensification of trade. Sea communication
regularly carried trade goods and people around the globe. The truly revolutionary
increase in trade occurred second half of the nineteenth century as the
free trade regime enforced by the British Empire coincided with the introduction
of steamboats and the opening of the Suez Canal. As a result, between
1850 and 1913 volumes of goods exchanged expanded tenfold (Topik 6). By
then financial innovations like bills of exchange, silver notes and sight
drafts would lessen the world's dependence on silver. However, this road
to globalization had been paved not with good intentions, but silver coins.
Expanding global trade intensified problems merchants had experienced
for centuries. Conducting transactions in unfamiliar currencies with differing
weights and of unknown purity exposed the merchant to some risk. Moreover,
profits remitted back to the home port in local specie might mean that
merchants lost a percentage of the coins' value in moneychangers' commissions
or that they received only the value of their coins' precious metal content.
Exchanging products for products avoided currency problems, but only if
there were mutually compatible goods on hand. International trade did
not depend on a standard currency, but a widely recognizable coin facilitated
the logistics of effecting purchases and remitting profits across continents
and oceans. Such a standard currency made calculating profits and keeping
track of expenses uniform over countries in the accounting systems of
companies.
Coins from the Spanish Empire filled this need. The combination of Spain's
abundant silver and fine mints made Spain the center of world coin production.
By the late eighteenth and early nineteenth century, the silver mines
of Mexico were the crown jewel of the Spanish Empire. The silver wealth
generated in Mexico's mines gave raise to mythology of excess. One Mexican
silver baron and owner of the famous Quintera mine, Señor Almeda,
marked his daughter's wedding by paving the path from the church to his
palacio with silver bars (White 29-30). However, the reality did not need
much embellishment; Mexico produced almost 80% of the world's silver between
1500 and 1800 (Barrett 237).
For two hundred
years, this silver from Mexico traveled in barely minted form. The single
mint in Mexico City produced mainly rough coins destined for the furnaces
of Europe until the 1730s. In a major shift in policy, King Felipe V shifted
most of Spanish finished coin production to Mexico. By dint of its abundant
silver, the Mexico City mint became the most important source of silver
coins in the world. It was also one of the most modern. Presses with the
latest screw technology stamped out well-centered coins with clear images
(AGN 66: 2). The images themselves changed to incorporate the most sophisticated
techniques available to discourage a number of creative fraudulent and
counterfeiting practices (see fig.1).1 Spanish assayists from the mint
in Seville monitored samples for image imperfections and tested coins
for variations in silver content.
The dedication to maintain the coins' buena ley or high quality and consistency
was notable especially considering the chronic shortage of government
funds. Neither Spain nor Mexico ever resorted to debasing the currency
to increase fiscal revenue. Spanish and Mexican coins never contained
less than 90% of their weight in silver and silver content fell only 5.9%
in total from the sixteenth to the end of the twentieth century (McMaster
372).2
Two coins dominated nineteenth-century production in Mexico: the Carolus
IIII real and the Republican peso (see figs. 3; 4). The recovery of Mexican
silver production and Spain's deepening financial problems during the
reign of Carlos IV (1788-1808) created a huge volume of silver coins bearing
his image. Under pressure from imperial wars with the stronger powers
of England and France, the Spanish crown teetered on bankruptcy. The desperate
king decreed in the Consolidación de Vales Reales that many of
the Catholic Church's extensive assets be converted into silver for shipment
to Spain as a "temporary" loan. As a result, the average silver
coin exports increased to 15-16 million a year by the 1800 decade (Garner
578). Minting increased to 21.3 million reales a year in 1800 from 12.8
million in the 1750s (Garner 580).
Until the Mexican independence movement began in 1810, locally minted
coins were faithful messengers of the metropolis. Coins minted in Mexico
reflected changing values of the Spanish state. The most salient was the
reform project of the late Bourbon kings that sought to modernize its
administration and centralize political power.3 The coins of Carlos III
followed this trend to its logical conclusion (see fig.2). The bust of
the monarch himself appeared on silver reales displacing the familiar
mares y mundos design. By the time Carlos IV ascended the Spanish throne
in 1778, the practice of using the king's portrait on coins was well established
(see fig. 3).4 The images on the coins succinctly summarized the Bourbon's
political message. The obverse showed the Bourbon symbol and organizing
principle of government, the bust of the king. The reverse defined the
Crown's historic claim to Spanish territory. The coat of arms incorporated
significant symbols of territory obtained through centuries of conquest
and marriages. The Pillars of Hercules represented Spain's Indies possessions
underlining the profoundly Spanish perspective of the coins. The reverse
was an imperial map defining symbolically the limits of sovereignty while
the obverse gave the locus of power or instrument through which it was
exercised.5
After independence leaders of the new Republic of Mexico sought to consolidate
the idea of Mexico as a nation. The prominence of Mexico's silver industry
and mint meant that coin production had a special significance and priority
for the new nation. Mexico had a standard coin design before it had a
permanent form of government (Vázquez 33).6 Moreover, the fine
quality and high productive capacity meant Mexico's leaders had access
to an important mass media for state propaganda. For a generation of new
Republican citizens, the coins reflected and created certain "catchsymbols,"
or distilled identity. The coin's design reaffirmed Mexico's political
independence in the symbolic space; postcolonial Mexican pesos retained
no image from their Bourbon predecessors. Nonetheless, Mexican coins followed
the same format of Bourbon coins: one side showed the symbol of government
while the other stated the historically-based claim to territory.
In fact the symbol that established this territorial legitimacy far predated
any Spanish intervention. The new Congress officially iconized an early
symbol of Creole identity. Republican coins pictured the eagle, snake
and cactus over the waters of Lake Texcoco that Aztecs sought to found
their capital Tenochtitlán, later Mexico City (see fig. 4).7 As
the symbol of the government on the reverse, the Mexican Congress choose
the Phrygian cap labeled "Libertad" surrounded by a sunburst.
The Congress, following French revolutionaries, choose this soft cap to
substitute the monarch's crown (Gumucio 75).8 The sunburst itself was
the truly extraordinary element of the design. Every Catholic should have
been familiar with the motif; saints, crosses, Mary and Jesus all feature
exactly the same design element as a symbol of sacred power or purity.
In the first flush of Republican idealism, the Congress sought to realign
the cosmology of the newly minted Republican citizens. The symbol acknowledged
the religious formation of the Mexican populace, but shifted its emphasis.
Power emanated from a new and profoundly secular notion. It was not the
other salient images, the liberty cap or eagle, that gave the peso its
name within Mexico; the coins were known as the radiant pesos (pesos de
resplandor) (Porrúa 96).
Images on Spanish reales and Mexican pesos communicated power, legitimacy
and territorial sovereignty. The audience of this mass media was primarily
the subjects and citizens who used the coins on a daily basis. The symbols
produced and reproduced the state uniting diverse peoples with little
else than geography in common. However, almost from the beginning of their
creation, these coins began to escape the strict confines of the Spanish
Empire. Coins were the silent partner of commercial expeditions, military
campaigns and covert smuggling operations. Once freed from the Spanish
Empire, these coins circulated throughout the globe following the path
of human economic relationships. Mexican-minted Spanish coins appeared
in the ports of the West Indies, Australia, the Baltic Sea, Russia, the
western, eastern and northern coasts of Africa, the United States, India,
Canada and Japan. By the early nineteenth century, the world commercial
system had been built not on faceless Spanish silver, but on Spanish silver
coins.
Spain bitterly lamented this loss of its silver. Spanish political economist
Guillermo Uztáriz wrote in a treatise to King Philip in 1742 that
Spain's most important assets, its pueblos, were bereft of silver coin
despite "thousands of millions" of pesos imported since the
discovery of America (30). To add insult to injury, this same Spanish
silver was being used against it by its competitors, England, Holland
and France to facilitate trade with the Levant in the land of their longtime
enemies, the Ottomans.
Uztáriz correctly identified that abundant imports of silver had
masked deep flaws in Spain's economy and that, as a result, Spanish silver
stopped only briefly in Spain. On the other side of the Mediterranean,
however, an Ottoman counterpart of Uztáriz had a different interpretation
of Spanish silver coins. Ottoman political economist, Selaniki, warned
his emperor that "(p)articularly the infidel rulers who are around
and about (us) were hard-working and persistent in (the selling of) their
gold and piaster. Through the execution of (their) orders and punitive
authority, they did not (let the currency) change (but) said 'the Ottoman
Empire is an example to us; see what kind of disorder will strike the
state and the wealth of the land'" (qtd. in Kafadar 100-01). As with
Uztáriz, Selaniki correctly identified a fundamental weakness of
his empire. The state of Ottoman public finances was poor and emperors
often resorted to debasing their currency, which allowed foreign coins
to invade more successfully than any European army.
Turkey
Imperial currency
had become so small and broken-faced that instead
of being the shining brightness of the garden and meadow of the empire
and the plentiful flower petals of the vernal park of rulership it has
now turned in appearance into drops of dew.
Ali (qtd. in Kafadar 88).
As with its
coins, the Ottoman Empire territory also began to resemble a drop of dew.
Insurgent movements in Egypt and Greece clipped off these economically
and strategically important regions in 1805 and 1821-30. The Ottoman state
also engaged in costly and ultimately unsuccessful military campaigns
against other imperial powers Austria, Russia and France. The pressure
these wartime expenses placed on Ottoman state's finances would be relieved
through the debasement of the Turkish kurux..
Although there had been a long tradition of currency devaluations or ihtilal
"disturbances" dating back to the sixteenth century, over Mahud
II's reign (1808-39) devaluations were especially severe (Kafadar). Imperial
mints struck ten series of coins and steadily decreased the silver content
from 5.9 grams to less than 1 gram (Pamuk 970). The inconsistency of the
key imperial currency made it less useful for large transactions. It was
instead used as a token currency for low value purchases such as what
an average citizen might buy for daily needs (Gerber and Gross). Foreign
currencies with a more reliable silver content began to prevail for larger
purchases and foreign trade.
The ability of the Ottoman Empire to enforce public use of its imperial
currency and political control were closely related (Pamuk 948). The heaviest
use of imperial coins found in the capital, Istanbul. Foreign coins infiltrated
even this political center. While changing her English sovereigns in 1866,
a British traveler received "a quantity of dirty paper of the value
of a few pence, German krentzers innumerable, an English shilling, and
a huge Turkish crown, mixed with francs and paras to one's utter bewilderment"
(Hornby 278). This very public debasement contributed to the nineteenth-century
trope of Turkish decay and wretchedness. Yet aside from the often-criticized
travelers' accounts, Turkish intellectuals noted the connection between
coins and public perceptions of the government's ability to rule. According
to historian Ali writing in 1581-1586, coins expressed sikke, which was
the written or physical form of hutbe, the greatness of royal prestige
and reminder of the respect and obedience due to the ruler (see fig.5;
Kafadar 86). The sad state of Ottoman coins reflected poorly, but truthfully
on the waning power and might of the emperor. The growing fiscal demands
on the Ottoman state were fulfilled by stopgap measures like currency
debasements to increase fiscal revenue rather than other more sustainable
means like raising internal taxes or foreign trade tariffs. Later in the
nineteenth century the Ottoman State again postponed these painful reforms
and resorted to foreign borrowing, something which would eventually result
in the loss of its fiscal sovereignty. The weak Ottoman currency foreshadowed
the political fate of the Empire as foreign coins made inroads into the
Ottoman economy.
However, the debased coins did not necessarily reflect the state of the
economy. Parts of the Ottoman Empire flourished over the nineteenth century
as Macedonia, western Anatolia and the coast of Syria began to develop
export agriculture (Pamuk 971). Outward-oriented trade introduced foreign
coins into the domestic economy signaling divided economic loyalty. Most
notable were foreign coins that circulated in the farther reaches of the
empire passing freely with Ottoman coins. Perhaps most disturbing were
rubles from Turkey's nemesis, Russia, that circulated in the Balkans and
the Trabazon area (Pamuk 974). The Balkans also drew Austrian currencies
and florins from nearby Italy, both of which circulated alongside Ottoman
piastres (Mackenzie 38, 41; Pamuk 974). In the Middle East, the Iranian
kran and the Indian rupee circulated in Iraq while the Maria Theresa thalers
were current in Yemen (Pamuk 974).
It was this last coin, the Maria Theresa thaler, that finally displaced
the Spanish real from the Middle East and East Africa in the early nineteenth
century. Maria Theresa dollars were minted in Austria. Following the empress'
death in 1780 all the subsequent coins featured the same design and this
same year (see fig. 6).9 Maria Theresa thalers came into widespread use
before Mexican pesos were widely exported. As a result, Maria Theresa
thalers, not Mexican pesos replaced the Spanish real.10 Spanish coins
did circulate and sometimes in areas quite close to the center of Turkish
political power, Istanbul. Writing at the turn of the nineteenth century,
chronicler al-Shihabi published an exchange rate table for common coins
of Lebanon. He mentions two coins with local names, the Mushakas piaster
and the bitaka franji (Gerber and Gross 355). Authors speculate that the
bitaka franji was the Imperial Hungarian coin known more commonly as Abu
Taka or pataque (Gerber and Gross 355). This was probably the Maria Theresa
thaler and the Mushakas piaster the Spanish real. In a coin hoard discovered
in Cairo, Egypt, researchers found an assortment of gold and silver coins
from the turn of the nineteenth century. The hoard consisted of sixty-three
larger silver coins minted in Istanbul dated from 1730-89, fifty Maria
Theresa thalers and fifty-four Spanish reales from Carolus III and Carolus
IIII (Seham 315). Many of the Ottoman coins said in Arabic: "Sultan
of the two continents and Khakan of the two seas, the sultan son of the
sultan." The fact that these coins were struck concurrently with
the Spanish coins, "mundos y mares," signifying Spanish mastery
over "two worlds and two seas" would not have escaped the contemporary
observer.
Foreign trade with local merchants introduced coins like the Spanish real
and the Maria Theresa thaler into Ottoman lands. But even as foreign trade
divided economic loyalties, Muslim merchants dealing with foreigners received
full legal rights (Kafadar 190). The Ottoman administration made no change
in the local merchants status as subjects. Moreover, there was no change
in the status of or understanding of that religious law that contributed
to the commercial dynamism of early Islam. Merchants played an integral
role in the Ottoman worldview. Four occupations made up Ottoman society:
men of the sword, men of the pen, men of commerce and men of husbandry
and agriculture (Kafadar 190). Each had their role in maintaining social
order in the circle of equity; "there can be no royal power without
the military, no military with wealth, no wealth with revenues, no revenues
without justice and equity" (Kafadar 190).
Nonetheless, local merchants involved in outward-oriented trade began
to shift their political loyalties to where their economic loyalties lie.
At the behest of foreign powers, the Ottoman Empire permitted special
local merchant courts to arbitrate legal disputes involving foreign nationals
(Owen 90). Local merchants began to acquire European citizenship, joining
French and British merchants in arbitrating against Turks in these commercial
tribunals (Owen 99).
Through these footholds, foreign influence infiltrated the Ottoman Empire.
In response, the Ottoman government did attempt arrest the process. To
set itself on firm financial ground, the Ottoman administration issued
interest bearing notes and contracted foreign loans. Part of these funds
were used to standardize the imperial currency. In 1844, the government
linked a new kurux to a gold lira in a money cleaning operation or tashih-i
sikke (Pamuk 971). The overwhelming indebtedness created by these reforms
eventually led to a financial crisis. To appease its foreign debtors the
Ottoman Empire relinquished control over its own finances to a consortium
of European interests (France and England primarily).
According to Turkish tradition, the first terrible sultans that swept
through Europe collected a great hoard of treasure, an Imperial Haznè,
and buried it deep in the Serraglio in Constantinople (MacFarlane 357-8).
Each sultan rising to the throne vowed not to touch it, but to increase
its volume through wise management of the empire's resources. At the prophesized
moment of crisis when infidels (Ghiaours) would come to conquer Constantinople,
the ruling sultan would empty the ancient chests to save the empire. For
the Ottoman Empire during the nineteenth century, the chests had been
turned inside out; foreign currency did not save the Empire's sovereignty,
but facilitated its demise.
India
As the Mughal Empire began to break up into princely states in the later
part of the eighteenth century, its administration's tight control over
imperial currency loosened and many new coins appeared. Despite the seemingly
chaotic situation, Spanish reales or Mexican pesos never played an important
domestic role.
The Mughal imperial mint system established precedents that prevented
any widespread domestic circulation of Spanish reales or Mexican pesos.
In the mid seventeenth to mid eighteenth century the Mughal along with
the Ming Empire were the two strongest and most highly developed commercial
economies in the world (Chaudhuri "World Silver" 73). The Mughal
government strictly oversaw the output of its imperial mints and in particular
its standard imperial coin, the silver rupee.11 Quite the opposite was
true for Southern India in territory outside of the Mughal Empire. Locally
controlled mints there struck coins of widely different, but generally
accepted denominational standards (Perlin 295). Regardless of the minted
standards, the message on all Indian coins was zealously controlled (see
fig.7). In accordance with Muslim law, the coins did not use any image.
The coins contained two essential scripts both written in Persian characters:
a passage from the Quran and the name of the reigning emperor. The coin
institutionalized the ruler's connection with Islam, which ordered and
legitimated political authority. While the phrase from the Quran differed,
the ruler's place in the Muslim worldview was most clearly expressed on
coins that stated "there is no other God than Allah and Muhammad
is his prophet." Together with the required emperor's name, the coin
established a clear hierarchy of authority and tied moral obligation to
political authority; respect God, obey the law and follow the emperor.
Like Turkish money, Indian coins expressed sikke, which was the physical
form of kuhtba, the right for the ruler's name to be read in the mosque.
Any foreign coin constituted a direct challenge to this basic equation.
Therefore under the Mughal administration, any silver destined to circulate
domestically first passed through the furnaces of the empire's mints in
such ports as Bengal, Gujarat or Madras (Moosvi 73). As the Mughal Empire
entered into a permanent decline by the second half of the 18th century,
political power began to decentralize. Mints proliferated as large holders
of prebendial rights (saranjamdar) assumed the right to strike their own
coins (Perlin 295-6). As the Mughal Empire proved unable to arrest growing
local control, Northern India coin production began to resemble that of
Southern India.
As a result at the turn of the century, over a thousand kinds of gold
and silver coins of various sizes, purities, weights and values circulated
as current in the Indian subcontinent (Mitra 23). Normally under such
conditions Spanish and Mexican coins invaded the domestic economy. Yet,
Spanish reales never played a significant domestic role in either Southern
or Mughal India. Rupees continued to dominate even important international
ports like Bengal and Calcutta (Williams 317, 321). From those cities
they spread all along the land route from the Black Sea to India and among
India's trading partners: Singapore, Malacca and Penang (Weeks; Williams
314-15).
Despite more local control, the strong incentives that bound key interests
to the enforcement of a local currency ensured that the Mughal minting
system continued in principle. Political leaders, no matter how local,
still depended on coins to construct and reinforce their authority. Well-placed
bureaucrats, Indian merchants and moneychangers, schroffs "were deeply
involved in collaborating with the mint officials in maintaining a semi-monopoly
in the supply of money" (Chaudhuri Trading World 308). These men
traditionally procured raw material, silver, for the mints, which they
continued to do. Incorporating the same men who dealt most with foreign
currency into the minting apparatus closed a potential entrance point
for Spanish or Mexican coins into the domestic economy. But also the loosening
central control opened new spaces for these key figures to take a proprietary
interest in official business. Some of the same men acquired the right
to strike coins, which could turn into a very profitable business. Not
every mint took this approach. Official concerns were more prevalent in
the mints of Kolhapur and Pune (Perlin 297). However, it was these divergent
strategies that created the noted multitude of coins.
Some mints specialized for market segments. The mints at Malwa and Malharshahi
became known for lower-quality coins that were accepted as current only
in their immediate vicinity (Perlin 304). Other local trade coins like
the Northern Indian rupee, the Southern pagoda and the Varanasi rupees
in Upper India circulated mainly within a certain territory (Perlin 301).
Notably, the regional trade coins like the Chandore rupee from Western
Deccan were struck in various mints with different administrations (Perlin
304). Other mints produced coins that closely matched the characteristics
of Spanish reales. The Arcot and Murshidabad circulated all over the Indian
subcontinent (see fig. 7; Perlin 305). Spanish coins did not circulate
because entrenched interests blocked their entrance and there were domestic
substitutes. Despite external perceptions of chaos or monetary anarchy,
the multitude of early nineteenth-century Indian coins filled distinct
niches in the Indian economy.
This diversity disappeared as the British East India Company began to
fill the administrative void left by the Mughal Empire. As early as 1806
the Company's Court of Directors proposed a single currency (Nambudiripad
12).12 When the Charter Act centralized executive and legislative authority
in the Council of Calcutta, the Council moved quickly and decisively.
With the Silver and Gold Coinage Act of 1835 the Company decreed a standard
silver rupee that came to dominate the subcontinent until 1893 (see fig.
8; Nambudiripad 15; Chandavarkar 770-71). Strong centralized control over
India's domestic currency closed India's huge domestic silver market just
as Mexican pesos began to circulate throughout the international commercial
circuits.
China
'The gold flower puts forth its leaves. The silver tree is full of blossom."
Wish for good luck put in a window on the Yangzi River by Chongqing.
Colquhoun 1: 104
The fastidiousness
of the Chinese respecting certain coins is like that of the Turks and
Arabs; and among them all it probably arose from the habit of receiving
coins of a certain stamp, from a uniform experience that they were always
good.
Williams 268
China's failure
to impose a standard silver coin reflected the freedom that made it such
a commercial success. However, the very reasons which prompted the freeform
currency situation led eventually to greater control and intervention
by foreign powers. Spanish and Mexican coins were the pioneers of imperialism
and the medium which made foreign trade possible. These coins were integrated
into the ritual life of China's inhabitants and given local names. However,
isolated examples show that Chinese if given the opportunity to choose
the content of their coins would have indigenized their symbols and images.
From 1644-1850, China's population rose from 100-150 million to 400 million
(Wang 434). Likewise, the economy grew and along with it the need for
a transaction currency. During the Ming dynasty, the Chinese Empire stopped
minting silver coins issuing instead paper bills. Although China's government
never stopped producing low-value copper coins, the Empire did not resume
regular silver coinage until the twentieth century (see fig. 9). Without
a government-issued silver coin, no universal standard obtained. The ungainly
organic solution that developed used silver bars known as sycee (see figs.
10; 11). Merchants weighed pieces of sycee on special silver scales, lí-tang,
snipping off pieces to make change. Although the weight could be determined
relatively easily, the purity was always in question (Williams 279).
Without a significant source of silver within its borders, any major silver
flows had to come from foreign trade. In the 16th and 17th centuries,
the Portuguese and Spanish and later the Dutch and English brought chests
of silver coins to exchange for tea, silk and ceramics. The demand for
silver and Spanish pieces of eight was great, "Chinas (sic) following
this with such an earnest eagerness as not to [be] beaten from the place
where they know it is, offringe their commodities to saile with an extraordinarie
importunitie, and will as soone part with their bloode as it, having once
possession" (Foster 228-9).
From Canton, the only legal port for foreign trade from 1757 until 1842,
Spanish coins traveled along the coast from Canton to Manchuria in the
ports and cities of Guangdong, Fujian, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Anhiu, and Chihui
(Kann 127). Spanish coins also spread internally following inland trade
routes following the great canals from Tienstin to Shanghai (Wang 434;
Allom 8). In the south (including the provinces on the southeast coast
and along the Yangzi valley up to Hunan) silver dollars circulated with
notes and taels (Wang 439; Kann). Areas more closely connected with the
coastal economy used silver dollars. A nineteenth-century traveler paid
new and chopped Mexican dollars during his Yangzi River voyage and sycee
silver for the more isolated Yunnan land journey (Wang 434; Colquhoun
1: 217). The closer the integration with the larger regional economy,
the more likely foreign coins would be accepted. Once the coins became
established, residents of the "Flowery Land" took them as their
own calling them the "flowered border" (Colquhoun 1: 217).13
In the far south on isolated Hainan island among the Le people, no silver
circulated at all. Higher value transactions were conducted with opium
balls (Henry 399).
As trade distributed silver among economically vibrant regions, the imperial
government redistributed it with the major flows heading north to the
capital of Beijing. As with governments around the world the relationship
between Chinese state and society was cemented through taxes. The people
above the Yangzi River going through Chongqing stated "(o)ur rulers
want money, and care little about the means by which it is attained. If
you know this, you know the principles and practice of the government"
(Gutzlaff 207). This silver tie that bound the Imperial Court and its
subjects was not consummated in foreign coins. The Kuping tael was the
official currency for all government obligations in silver (Kann 153).14
People made direct tax payments to "money shops" or banks (Davis
2: 371). These intermediaries accepted any old coins or bits of sycee
silver. The silver was melted down into a Kuping tael and sent to government
coffers (Kann 153; Williams 177). Melting sanitized the silver before
reaching the celestial port. Any evidence of its past as a foreign coin
or wayward piece of silver was erased. The distinction was made quite
clear in common usage. Foreign coins were called in general "fan-yin"
or barbarian silver, "fan-ping" or barbarian cake, and "yang-ch'ien"
or foreign coin (Yang 48-9).
Accordingly, foreign silver coins did not play a large role in official
ritual and silver only a minor part. For example, during the celebration
of the Emperor's [Káng-hsi] sixtieth birthday "a vast number
of aged, but healthy men
(arrived)
from all the provinces. His
Majesty gave to each of them twelve silver tael, a coin worth about five
shillings, together with a gown of yellow silk, which is the imperial
colour. Later he gave them a mandarin's suit, a staff, an inkstand and
other things" (Ripa 87). The political and cultural brokers did not
attach much cultural value on silver either as a metal or color. Silk,
calligraphy and poetry were much more important. If the Spanish and Mexican
silver pesos did not infiltrate official ritual, neither did the images
on the coins communicate any direct subversion of Chinese symbols of state.
Government trade and trade constituted the two major forces within China
that moved silver and determined the currency that was available for commercial
purposes. The silver that circulated in Beijing and the north was largely
sycee. At the northern trade port of Tienstin, resident merchants carried
on a regular trade in Cantonese products paid in sycee silver. "The
quantity of it was so great that there seemed to be no difficulty in collecting
thousands of taels at the shortest notice" (Gutzlaff 129). In the
north the sycee system using taels prevailed. In the south and along the
coast, Spanish reales and Mexican pesos passed as current. The place where
the two met was Shanghai. Shanghai was also exemplary of the struggle
that faced China during the nineteenth century. Foreign intervention opened
Shanghai's ports. The pressure created by a boom in foreign trade came
to bear on the established and trusted Spanish Carolus IIII real. Only
under extreme conditions provoked by a severe coin shortage did people
adopt a new currency standard. The growing outward orientation of Shanghai
exposed it to new pressures. The city found itself at the intersection
of domestic and international trade and imperial and foreign governance
all of which was mediated through local tradition.
For two-hundred fifty years regardless of domestic business cycles, China
could always count on a steady silver inflow from its European trading
partners. However, in the early nineteenth century, Chinese leaders noticed
a serious shortage of silver within the empire. The viceroy of Fujian
sent a report to the emperor in 1824 saying that "silver and copper
coins have become very disproportioned in their relative values; the former
rising, and the latter falling to an unusual degree" (qtd. in Davis
2: 370). For the viceroy, this shift in value constituted a serious problem
for internal order since the military had been traditionally paid in copper
cash and were experiencing a serious loss of value in silver terms. In
reality, Chinese government was already aware of the drain in silver.
The Chinese court had prohibited its export by imperial order as early
as 1814 in the nineteenth year of Chia-ch'ing (Morse Chronicles 337).
Later economic historians would confirm the suspicions of the Chinese
court. Due to the growth in the opium trade, 50 million dollars were extracted
from China by British ship mostly to India from 1818 to 1834 (Kann 127).15
Chinese leaders understood the problem. It is less clear, though, how
much administrators realized the rise in silver prices resulted not only
from the opium trade, but also from silver shortages stemming from over
ten years of political and economic turmoil in the Spanish Americas. Regardless,
the more vigorous enforcement steps that administrators took to remedy
high silver prices would have permanent ramifications for internal stability
and the sovereignty of the country.
Shortly after, the Chinese court began to put teeth into its many dead
letter pronouncements against the opium agents operating off the coast
of China. Captain Charles Elliot wrote on the 26th of January 1838 "there
seems, my lord, no longer any room to doubt that the court has finally
determined to suppress, or more probably most extensively to check, the
opium trade. The immense, and it must be said the most unfortunate increase
of the supply during the last four years, the rapid growth of the east
coast trade in opium, and the continued drain of the silver, have no doubt
greatly alarmed the government" (qtd. in Davis 1: 24). Persecuted
on the coast, traffickers took to the rivers of China and eventually created
the spark for the first of two Opium Wars (1840 and 1856).
This series of events revolutionized Shanghai. As a result of the Opium
Wars, the ports of Shanghai were opened to foreign trade in 1842. Its
close location to the silk of Suzhou and tea of Hanzhou and excellent
port facilities quickly made it a hub of international trade along with
the new English colony of Hong Kong. Despite the rise in trade, Shanghai
merchants did not change their currency. The Shanghai were seemingly obsessed
with the Carolus IIII dollar called "old head" or ssu-kung-yin
dollars".16 At one point in the premium paid for Carolus dollars
reached as high as 40% above Mexican dollars and over 30% above a tael's
weight of silver (Williams 198-199). Reales of his son Fernando VII with
an equal amount of silver sold for a discount of 30% (McMaster 389). Stated
another way, by demanding Carolus reales Shanghaise received 30-40% less
silver than instruments with nearly identical characteristics. The world
was scoured for old Carolus reales as pundits noted incredulously the
irrationality of the Shanghaise.
However, the demand did not come solely from the Shanghai. Only strong
demand from the interior silk and tea regions could have sustained such
high valuations. In each case, the problem lay not in irrationality. It
is hard to argue that the silk and tea producers were backwards country
folk when the region had a centuries-old tradition of foreign-oriented
plantation production. Chinese in the interior recognized the Carolus
coins as premium stores of value and unimpeachable medium of exchange.
These functions became even more important in the midst of political and
economic turmoil. Generic silver or any silver coin did not fulfill the
same need; the images on the coins were communicated a guarantee of its
value. The coins were so cherished that it took nothing less than the
acute silver shortage caused by the opium trade plus a global silver shortage
to induce Chinese consumers to switch from Spanish reales de a ocho to
another standard coin, the Mexican peso.17
Once the change was made, consumers clung to Mexican pesos as they had
to the Carolus dollar (Williams 198-199). In sixty years after the 1850s
an estimated 400 to 500 million ying-yang or eagle dollars as the Mexican
dollars were known circulated or were hoarded in China (Kann 145; Yang
48-9). The conversion even reached the Chinese interior. Older Spanish
reales began reappearing in maritime ports as people substituted the Mexican
pesos (Williams 269).
The switch to Mexican pesos was not even, uniform or even guaranteed.
The North China Herald reported that most Shanghai retail merchants in
the 1850s still used the Carolus silver dollar for their unit of account
while wholesale merchants used the tael (Wang). Some firms around the
1856 took advantage of the par valuation between Carolus reales and Shanghai
taels to switch accounting units (Kann 129). The storied Hongkong Shanghai
Bank (HSBC) in Shanghai did not convert its accounting system to Shanghai
taels until 1921 (Lagerberg 412). In Formosa, there was no currency change.
The Carolus dollar remained the standard currency there until the Japanese
took it in 1895 (Kann 128). In general, ports south of Shanghai adopted
the Mexican dollar while those north remained on the nominal tael standard.
The large discrepancy between the Carolus coins' silver content and its
market value highlighted the conflict between local beliefs and larger
outside economic forces. Part of the reason that the Carolus real was
so difficult to replace was that it was integrated into people's lives
in a meaningful way.
In Shanghai, the economic function of the cherished Spanish real also
melded with its ritual use. Ritual consumption of token goods and food
played an important symbolic role is burial ceremonies and New Year's
celebrations to honor gods or ancestors. Figuring prominently among the
food and paper possessions was laminated coins symbolizing Spanish reales.
Mainly women manufactured these coins placing a coating of tinfoil over
paper (Taylor 118-19). The ritual use reflected the Spanish coins symbolism
as representative of wealth and abundance within the pantheon of significant
possessions.
Also in Shanghai, at the beginning of each year, households placed a painted
figure on a scrap of paper above the cooking range (Taylor 252-53). This
kitchen god observed the goings-on of the family during the year. At year's
end, "a very adhesive kind of candy is placed before his godship,
made in the form of Spanish dollars and lumps of Sycee silver." The
stickiness of the candy was to "seal the lips of the god when he
is sent up to the chief of the Chinese celestial deities to report the
conduct of the different members of the family during the past year; so
that when he is question (sic), he cannot open his lips to relate the
deviations from rectitude he may have observed, but can only nod his head,
which is taken as signifying that all have behaved will in the family
where he presided." Silver not only sealed the lips of the god, but
also the union between the secular and sacred. It was the product and
participant in good fortune.
Foreign silver coins gained entry into both the Chinese economic and ritual
realms. However, the coins did not pass through Chinese hands unscathed.
Spanish and Mexican coins were sometimes covered with tiny Chinese character
chopmarks that adulterated the strictly foreign content of the coins'
images (see fig. 12). To validate the coin's value, merchants in southern
ports like Canton and Hong Kong used a very small metal stamp to imprint
its Chinese character on the coin (Kann 128-9). Less scrupulous moneychangers
chiseled out their chopmark removing a very small portion of the silver.
In northern ports and Shanghai, the moneychangers signed their chop in
ink (Kann).
Chopmarks were used partially in response to widespread counterfeiting.
There was a thriving domestic industry to mass produce counterfeited Spanish
and Mexican coins. In Shunteh south of Canton, factories with as many
as 100 workmen specialized in a variety of fakes, alterations and alloyed
coins (Williams 270). One of the most common was replacing the core with
lead. The problem was so prevalent that there was said to be both a forgery
and detection manual. Some forgeries were nearly perfect. The images on
a Chinese forgery of a Republican peso were so accurate they invited even
specialists to speculate that the incorrect assayers' initials and mint
marks were intentional (Halliday).18 The British East India Company itself
forged dies and hired a Canton mint to manufacture Carolus III coins in
1779. The Company was outswindled with unscrupulous minters there quickly
debased the coin to .600 (Hubbard 58).
In response, consumers demanded that the value of the coins be validated.
Chopmarks guaranteed the full value of silver content. If the holder found
a coin to be deficient, the merchant was obligated to restitute loss.
In this way, chopmarks imposed a second authority and responsibility over
the coins. The contract of value was no longer between the Spanish king
or the Mexican Republic, but with the local moneychanger. With this visa,
the foreign coins could circulate through the country. The act of localizing
the content, however, destroyed the coins. Stamping mutilated their shape
(see fig. 13). As different hands chopped the coins, the awls pushed them
out into the form of mushrooms. These broken dollars lost the distinctive
symbols that indicated their value. Without these distinctive marks, coins
were only worth their weight in silver.
Chopmarks represented an organic strategy to indigenize the images on
foreign coin for a Chinese audience. In another instance, a coin indicates
that Chinese might have sought to include images that better reflected
themselves. In an old box of coins from China, John Halliday found an
1819 Mexico City chopped coin of Ferdinand VII first believed to be a
forgery. However, the weight and specific gravity showed it to be a genuine
coin. An anonymous engraver had modified the king's portrait with a hand
tool making him look distinctly Chinese (Halliday 45). It may have been
a small and anonymous piece of resistance dropped in among the hundreds
of millions of other coins, but it was a strong opinion that the coins
did not represent the people they served.
Conclusion
Silver "is
a vital resource, it is soft and seductive, but its national identity
is utterly superficial and easily erased, its loyalties skin deep. Its
value is unquestionable but its values dubious--it serves all masters
and none"
Christopher Tomlins 1453
Some traditional monies like cowry shells successfully made the transition
to an interregional currency. However, only precious metals like gold
and silver were able to create the economic equivalences that tied the
world together. Abstractly silver and gold provoked a convergence to an
ultimate universal value-that of a single commodity price for precious
metals. If the commodification of precious metals rendered them a relatively
valueless value, Spanish and Mexican coins were a different issue. The
Carolus IIII coin reached market valuations up to 40% over the intrinsic
value of its silver. His son's coins and Mexican pesos, which should have
fulfilled the same niche as the Carolus IIII coins and contained exactly
the same amount of silver, circulated at a discount. The symbols and images
served a vital role, much different from plain silver or any generic coin.
Spanish and Spanish American minted coins circulated first through Europe
then the Mediterranean, Africa and Asia along established trading routes.
Spanish reales de a ocho and later Mexican pesos became the world's most
widely distributed coin. Through the vector of expanding European trade,
the Spanish then Mexican coin carried with it locally significant messages
to the rest of the world in perhaps the world's most effective and pervasive
medium. Local merchants exchanged their economic products for cultural
by-products. Foreign coins were important first colonizing forces entering
even before foreign merchant trade reached a city. These coins informed
citizens of alternate states and their pantheon of meaningful symbols.
Where these images did not conflict with official state icons, the coins
were tolerated obliquely.
Once circulating within the national and local economies Spanish coins
challenged local political imagistic purity on a daily basis. These coins
were extremely hard to eradicate. As nations began to take firmer control
over their own official projection, nations began to demonetize the Spanish
real and Mexican peso. Starting in the 1850s Canada, Japan and the US
recognized only their own official state currency as legal tender (McMaster
375. Enforcing a state currency in the face of entrenched local acceptance
and trust of its citizens required a sustained and serious administrative
effort. Countries without that administrative power also found themselves
accepting dictates of other nations on international trade regulation,
legal arbitration and tax treatment. Spanish and Mexican coins did not
imply a political confrontation; however, it was a political challenge
to test the state's capability.
Fig. 1. Mundos y mares or pillar dollar. 1754. Mexico City. Casa de Moneda
de México. Historia Numismática. <http://www.cmonedam.com.mx/cmm/cmm_bastidores.htm>
Fig. 2. Carolus III real. 1772. Mexico City. Casa de Moneda de México. Historia Numismática. <http://www.cmonedam.com.mx/cmm/cmm_bastidores.htm>
Fig. 3. Carolus IIII real. 1803. Mexico City. Casa de Moneda de México. Historia Numismática. <http://www.cmonedam.com.mx/cmm/cmm_bastidores.htm>
Fig. 4. Republican peso. 1854. Mexico City. Casa de Moneda de México. Historia Numismática. <http://www.cmonedam.com.mx/cmm/cmm_bastidores.htm>
Fig 5. Gold coin of Mahmud 1, 1730. Istanbul. Turkish Cultural Foundation. The Turkish Ottoman and Seljuk Coins. <http://www.turkishculture.org/monetary/coinage.html>
Fig. 6. Maria Theresa Thaler. 1780 Maria Theresa Silver Thaler. <http://www.24carat.co.uk/mariatheresathaler.html>
Fig. 7. Parekh, Varun. Alamgir II Arcot Silver Rupee. Minted at Madras and struck in Arcot from 1759 to 1806 with frozen regal year 6. Ancient India Coins Prior to 1857. <http://www.angelfire.com/on2/coins/ancient.html>
Fig. 8. Parekh, Varun Victoria Silver Rupee. Minted at Madras in 1862. British India Coins 1857-1947. <http://www.angelfire.com/on2/coins/british.html>
Fig. 9. Belyaev, Vladimir. Bronze coin. Beijing 1644. Shun Chih Coins. <http://www.sportstune.com/chinese/coins/shunchih.html>
Fig. 10. Shan-Si sycee. Example of China silver sycee. <http://www.charm.ru/library/sycee2.htm>
Fig. 11. Jiang-Si sycee. Example of China silver sycee. <http://www.charm.ru/library/sycee2.htm>
Fig. 12. Tai, Stephen. Chopmarked Mexican Republican peso. Chopmarks on 5 Mexican Silver Dollars. December 18, 1999 <http://www.charm.ru/coins/misc/chopmarks.shtml>
Fig. 13. Tai, Stephan. Chopmarked Fernando VII real. Chopped Dollars. Feb. 28, 1998 <http://www.charm.ru/library/fsilver2.htm>
Works Consulted
Casa De Moneda. Archivo General de la Nación, Mexico City.
Casa de Moneda de México. Carolus III real. 1772. Mexico City.
Historia
Numismática. <http://www.cmonedam.com.mx/cmm/cmm_bastidores.htm>
---. Carolus IIII real. 1803. Mexico City. Casa de Moneda de
México. Historia Numismática. <http://www.cmonedam.com.mx/cmm/cmm_bastidores.htm>
---. Mundos y mares or pillar dollar. 1754. Mexico City. Historia Numismática.
<http://www.cmonedam.com.mx/cmm/cmm_bastidores.htm>
---. Republican peso. 1854. Mexico City. Historia Numismática.
<http://www.cmonedam.com.mx/cmm/cmm_bastidores.htm>
"Guaranteeing Mexican Dollars." The Numismatist XVII (1904).
"Trade Dollars at a Premium." The Numismatist XIX (1906).
Adams, E. H. "The Commercial Dollar." The Numismatist XXIV (1911):
119-20.
Allom, Thomas. The Chinese Empire: Historical and Descriptive. Illustrating
the
Manners and Customs of the Chinese, in a Series of Steel Engravings, from
Original Sketches. London: London Printing and Publishing Co., 1858.
Anderson, Benedict R. O. G. Imagined Communities : Reflections on the
Origin and
Spread of Nationalism. Rev. and extended ed. London ; New York: Verso,
1991.
Aòhmad, Behbahåanåi, and öKöhudåa Baököhsh
Oriyanòtal Pablik Låaibreråi. India in
the Early 19th Century : An Iranian's Travel Account : Translation of
Mirat Ul-Ahwal-I Jahan Numa. Patna: Khuda Bakhsh Oriental Public Library,
1996.
Applebaum, Norman I. "The British Trade Dollar." The Numismatist
LXXXI (1968).
Attman, Artur. American Bullion in the European World Trade, 1600-1800.
Acta Regiae
Societatis Scientiarum Et Litterarum Gothoburgensis. Humaniora 26. Göteborg:
Kungl. Vetenskaps- och Vitterhets Samhället, 1986.
Ball, J. Dyer, and E. T. C. Werner. Things Chinese; or, Notes Connected
with China. 5th
ed. London,: John Murray, 1926.
Barrett, Ward. "World Bullion Flows. 1450-1800." The Rise of
Merchant Empires :
Long-Distance Trade in the Early Modern World, 1350-1750. Eds. James D.
Tracy and University of Minnesota. Center for Early Modern History. Studies
in Comparative Early Modern History. Cambridge ; New York: Cambridge University
Press, 1990. 224-54.
Belyaev, Vladimir. Bronze coin. 1644. Beijing. Shun Chih Coins.
<http://www.sportstune.com/chinese/coins/shunchih.html>
Braudel, Fernand. Civilization and Capitalism, 15th-18th Century. Berkeley:
University
of California Press, 1992.
Brij, Narain. Indian Economic Life : Past and Present. Delhi, New Delhi:
Neeraj Pub.
House; Distributed by D.K. Publishers' Distributors, 1984.
Butler, Dudley. "The Thalers Talk of Their Home Towns." The
Numismatist LVI (1943).
Carroll, Thomas. "The Case for the Spain Dollar." The Numismatist
LXVIII (1955).
Carruthers, Bruce G. and Sarah Babb. "The Color of Money and the
Nature of Value:
Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America." American Journal of Sociology
101 (1996).
Carruthers, Bruce G and Wendy Nelson Espeland. "Money, Meaning and
Morality."
American Behaviorial Scientist 41.10 (1998): 1384-408.
Cervantes, Manuel, and Sociedad Mexicana de Geografía y Estadística.
La Moneda En
México. Mexico,, 1954.
Chaudhuri, K. N. The Trading World of Asia and the English East India
Company, 1660-
1760. Cambridge Eng. ; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1978.
---. "World Silver Flows and Monetary Factors as a Force of International
Economic
Integration, 1658-1758." Metals and Monies in an Emerging Global
Economy. Eds. Dennis Owen Flynn and Arturo Giráldez. An Expanding
World ; V. 14. Aldershot, Hampshire, Great Britain ; Brookfield, Vt.:
Variorum, 1997. xl, 364.
Chaunu, Pierre. Les Philippines Et Le Pacifique Des Ibériques (Xvie,
Xviie, Xviiie
Siècles); Introduction Méthodologique Et Indices D* Activité.
Ports, Routes, Trafics ; 11. Paris,: S. E. V. P. E. N., 1960.
Cheong, W.E. "Trade and Finance in China." Business History
7.1 (1965): 34-56.
Chiang, Chung-ch'uan. Illustrations of Chinese Gold, Silver, and Nickel
Coins. Asia,
1939.
Colquhoun, Archibald R. Across Chryse, Being the Narrative of a Journey
of Exploration
through the South China Border Lands from Canton to Mandalay. New York,:
Scribner Welford, 1883.
Conder, J. Syria and Asia Minor Vol.1-2. London: J. Duncan, 1824.
Crosby, Alfred W. The Columbian Exchange; Biological and Cultural Consequences
of
1492. Westport, Conn.,: Greenwood Pub. Co., 1972.
Crump, Thomas. "Money and Number: The Trojan Horse of Language."
Man, New
Series 13.4 (1978): 503-18.
Davenport, John S. The Silver Dollars of Africa. A Type Catalogue of the
Silver Dollar
Size Coins of Africa Including Patterns, Fantasy and Private Issues. Racine,
Wis.,: Whitman, 1959.
Davey, Richard. The Sultan and His Subjects. Chatto & Windus, London,
1907.
Davis, John Francis. The Chinese: A General Description of the Empire
of China and Its
Inhabitants. London: Murray, 1857.
Doolittle, Justus. Social Life of the Chinese: With Some Account of Their
Religious,
Governmental, Educational, and Business Customs and Opinions. London:
S. Low, son, and Marston, 1868.
Durkheim, Émile. The Elementary Forms of the Religious Life. 2nd
ed. London: Allen
and Unwin, 1976.
Fairbank, John King, Martha Henderson Coolidge, and Richard J. Smith.
H.B. Morse,
Customs Commissioner and Historian of China. Lexington: University Press
of Kentucky, 1995.
Florescano, Enrique. La Bandera Mexicana : Breve Historia De Su Formación
Y
Simbolismo. 1. ed. México, D.F.: Fondo de Cultura Económica,
1998.
Flynn, Dennis Owen, and Arturo Giráldez. Metals and Monies in an
Emerging Global
Economy. An Expanding World ; V. 14. Aldershot, Hampshire, Great Britain
; Brookfield, Vt.: Variorum, 1997.
Flynn, Dennis O and Arturo Giraldez. "Arbitrage, China, and World
Trade in the Early
Modern Period." Journal of the Economic and Social History of the
Orient [Netherlands] 38.4 (1995): 429-48.
Foster, William. The English Factories in India, 1634-1636, a Calendar
of Documents in
the India Office, British Museum and Public Record Office. Oxford,: The
Clarendon press, 1911.
Garner, Richard L. "Exportaciones De Circulante En El Siglo Xviii
(1750-1810)."
Historia Mexicana XXXI.Abril-Junio (1982): 544-98.
Garnett, Lucy Mary Jane. Turkish Life in Town and Country. New York, London,:
G.P.
Putnam's Sons, 1904.
Geerle, Jonh H. "The Silver Mystery of China." American Numismatic
Society XXXIII
(1920): April 1920.
Geertz, Clifford. "Thick Description: Toward an Interpretive Theory
of Culture." The
Interpretation of Culture: Selected Essays. New York, NY: Basic Books,
1973.
Gerber, Haim and Nachum T. Grossman. "Inflation or Deflation in Nineteenth-Century
Syria and Palestine." Journal of the Economic History 40.2 (1980):
351-58.
Great Britain. Naval Intelligence Division. China Proper. 1944-45. Prepared
by the
Cambridge subcentre. Cambridge?, 1944.
Greenberg, Michael. British Trade and the Opening of China, 1800-42. Cambridge
Studies in Economic History. Cambridge Eng.: University Press, 1951.
Grove, Frank W. Coins of Mexico. Lawrence, Mass.: Quarterman Publications,
1981.
Gumucio, Fernando Baptista. Las Monedas De La Independencia, 1808-1827.
Colección
Cultural Centenario. Ed. Cerveceria La Taquina S.A. La Paz, Bolivia: Editorial
Aeronautica, Centro de Estudios Sociales, 1995.
Guttag, Julius, and E. H. Adams. Catalogue of the Collection of Julius
Guttag;
Comprising the Coinage of Mexico, Central America, South America and the
West Indies. 2 ed. New York,: Quarterman Publications, 1974.
Gutzlaff, Karl Friedrich August, and William Ellis. Journal of Three Voyages
Along the
Coast of China, in 1831, 1832, & 1833, with Notices of Siam, Corea,
and the
Loo-Choo Islands. London,: F. Westley and A.H. Davis, 1834.
Halil, Halid. The Diary of a Turk. London: Adam and Charles Black, 1903.
Hart, Robert, et al. Entering China's Service : Robert Hart's Journals,
1854-1863. Harvard
East Asian Monographs ; 125. Cambridge, Mass.: Council on East Asian Studies
Harvard University : Distributed by the Harvard University Press, 1986.
---. The I. G. In Peking : Letters of Robert Hart, Chinese Maritime Customs,
1868-1907.
Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1975.
Heiss, Aloïss. Descripción General De Las Monedas Hispano-Cristianas
Desde La
Invasión De Los Árabes. Zaragoza,: L. Marquina, 1962.
Helleiner, Eric. "National Currencies and National Identities."
American Behavioral
Scientist 41.10 (1998): 1409-37.
Henry, Benjamin Couch. Ling-Nam: Or, Interior Views of Southern China
; Including
Explorations in the Hitherto Untraversed Island of Hainan. London: S.W.
Partridge, 1886.
Herrera, Adolfo. El Duro: Estudio De Los Reales De a Ocho Españoles
Y De Las
Monedas De Igual O Aproximado Valor Labradas En Los Dominios De La Corona
De España. Ed. Real Academica de la Historia. Vol. 1-2. Madrid:
J. Lacoste, 1914.
Hornby, Mrs. Edmund. In and around Stamboul. Philadelphia: J. Challen
& son, Lindsay
& Blakiston, 1866.
Hsü, Immanuel Chung-yueh. The Rise of Modern China. 6th ed. New York:
Oxford
University Press, 2000.
Huc, Évariste Régis. A Journey through the Chinese Empire.
New York,: Harper, 1855.
Jesus De, P.L. "Early Coins of the Philippines." The Numismatist
LX (1947).
Jiang-Si sycee.Example of China silver sycee. <http://www.charm.ru/library/sycee2.htm>
Kafadar, Cemal. "When Coins Turned into Drops of Dew and Bankers
Became Robbers
of Shadows: The Boundaries of Ottoman Economic Imagination at the End
of the
Sixteenth Century." Ph.D dissertation. McGill University, 1986.
Kann, Eduard. The Currencies of China ; an Investigation of Silver &
Gold Transactions
Affecting China, with a Section on Copper. 2d , rev. ed. Shanghai,: Kelly
& Walsh, 1927.
Lagerberg, J. de. "Accounts to Be Made in Silver Dollars at Amoy,
China." The
Numismatist XXXIV (1921): 412.
Leyshon, Andrew, and N. J. Thrift. Money Space : Geographies of Monetary
Transformation. International Library of Sociology. London ; New York:
Routledge, 1997.
López Rosado, Diego G. Historia Del Peso Mexicano. 1. ed. México:
Fondo de Cultura
Económica, 1975.
Lynch, John. "Origins of Spanish American Independence." The
Cambridge History of
Latin America. Ed. Leslie Bethell. Vol. III. Cambridge England ; New York:
Cambridge University Press, 1984. 3-50.
MacFarlane, Charles. Constantinople in 1828; a Residence of Sixteen Months
in the
Turkish Capital and Provinces: With an Account of the Present State of
the Naval
and Military Power, and of the Resources of the Ottoman Empire. 2d ed.
London,:
Saunders and Otley, 1829.
Mackenzie, Georgiana Mary Muir Mackenzie, and Adelina Paulina Irby. Travels
in the
Slavonic Provinces of Turkey-in-Europe. 4th ed. London: Daldy Isbister
& Co., 1877.
Maria Theresa Thaler. 1780 Maria Theresa Silver Thaler.
<http://www.24carat.co.uk/mariatheresathaler.html>
Martin, W. A. P. A Cycle of Cathay: Or, China, South and North. Edinburgh:
O.
Anderson and Ferrier, 1896.
McMaster, John. "Aventuras Asiaticas Del Peso Mexicano." Historia
Mexicana VIII.
Enero-marzo (1959): 372-99.
Mitra, Debendra Bijoy. Monetary System in the Bengal Presidency, 1757-1835.
Calcutta:
K.P. Bagchi & Co., 1991.
Mooser, Sawyer Mc A. "Additional Notes on the Maria Theresa Thaler."
The
Numismatist LVIII (1945).
Moosvi, Shireen. "The Silver Influx, Money Supply, Prices and Revenue
Extraction in
Mughal India." Journal of the Economic and Social History of the
Orient [Netherlands] 30.1 (1987): 47-94.
Morineau, Michel. Incroyables Gazettes Et Fabuleux Métaux : Les
Retours Des Trésors
Américains D'après Les Gazettes Hollandaises (Xvie-Xviiie
Siècles). London ; New York, Paris: Cambridge University Press
; Maison des sciences de l'homme, 1985.
Morse, Hosea Ballou. The Chronicles of the East India Company, Trading
to China,
1635-1834. Oxford,: The Clarendon Press, 1926.
Morse, Hosea Ballou, F. L. Hawks Pott, and A. Théophile Piry. The
Trade and
Administration of the Chinese Empire. Vol.1-2. Shanghai: Kelly and Walsh,
1908.
Mossman, Philip L., and American Numismatic Society. Money of the American
Colonies and Confederation : A Numismatic, Economic and Historical Correlation.
Numismatic Studies No. 20. New York: American Numismatic Society, 1993.
Museo Nacional de Arte (Mexico), and Universidad Nacional Autónoma
de México.
Instituto de Investigaciones Estéticas. De La Patria Criolla a
La Nación Mexicana, 1750-1860. Pinceles De La Historia. 1. ed.
Mexico, Mexico City, Mexico: Banamex ; Patronato del Museo Nacional de
Arte : Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México Instituto
de Investigaciones Estéticas ; Mexico : CONACULTA INBA, 2000.
Nelson, Julie A. "One Sphere or Two?" American Behavioral Scientist
41.10 (1998):
1467-71.
Norweb, Collection. "The Norweb Collection : Cleveland, Ohio, U.S.A.
: Mexican &
Central American Coins." Ed. Spink & Son. Dallas, TX: Christie's,
1985. v.
Orozco y Becerra, Manuel. "Moneda En Mexico." Diccionario Universal
Y De
Geografia. Vol. V. Mexico City: F Excalante y Co, 1854.
Parekh, Varun. Alamgir II Arcot Silver Rupee. Minted at Madras and struck
in Arcot
from 1759 to 1806 with frozen regal year 6. Ancient India Coins Prior
to 1857. <http://www.angelfire.com/on2/coins/ancient.html>
---. Victoria Silver Rupee. Minted at Madras in 1862. British India Coins
1857-1947.
<http://www.angelfire.com/on2/coins/british.html>
Parry, Jonathan P., and Maurice Bloch. Money and the Morality of Exchange.
Cambridge
England; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989.
Perlin, Frank. "Money-use in Late Pre-colonial India and the International
Trade in
Currency Media." John F. Richards and Joint Committee on South Asia.
The Imperial Monetary System of Mughal India. Delhi ; New York: Oxford
University Press, 1987.
Polk, William Roe, and Richard L. Chambers. Beginnings of Modernization
in the
Middle East; the Nineteenth Century. Chicago,: University of Chicago Press,
1968.
Prakash, Om. European Commercial Expansion in Early Modern Asia. An Expanding
World ; V. 10. Aldershot, England ; Brookfield, USA: Variorum, 1997.
Pamuk, Sevket. "Money in the Ottoman Empire, 1326-1914." Ed.
Halil Inalcik and
Donald Quataert. An Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire.
1st paperback ed. Cambridge ; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997.
Ramírez, Santiago. Introduction. Indagaciones Sobre La Amonedacion
En Nueva España.
By Fausto de Elhuyar. Mexico: Filomeno Mata, 1880.
Ramsden, F. R.N.S. "Foreign Money in China." The Numismatist
XXIII (1910): 33-34.
Rawski, Thomas G. Economic Growth in Prewar China. Berkeley: University
of
California Press, 1989.
Raychaudhuri, Tapan, and Irfan Habib. The Cambridge Economic History of
India.
Cambridge Eng. ; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1983.
Richards, John F. Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and Early Modern
Worlds.
Durham, N.C.: Carolina Academic Press, 1983.
Richards, John F., and Joint Committee on South Asia. The Imperial Monetary
System of
Mughal India. Delhi ; New York: Oxford University Press, 1987.
Ripa, Matteo. Memoirs of Father Ripa: During Thirteen Years' Residence
at the Court of
Peking in the Service of the Emperor of China, with an Account of the
Foundation of the College for the Education of Young Chinese at Naples.
London: J. Murray, 1844.
Ruiz, Luis Enrique. "A "Three Quinari" Anniversary."
Numismatic Society Mexico
Bulletin VII (1967).
Salmeron, Antonio Deana. La Casa De Moneda De Durango; Acunaciones De
Plata,
1824-1895. Puebla, Mexico: Impresos San Diego, 1983.
Sar¸ Mehmet, Paðsa, and Walter Livingston Wright. Ottoman Statecraft;
the Book of
Counsel for Vezirs and Governors (NaòsåaIòh Èul-Vèuzera
VeL-Èumera) of Sari
Meòhmed Pasha, the Defterdåar. Princeton Oriental Texts ;
V. 2. London, Princeton,: H. Milford Oxford University press; Princeton
university press, 1935.
Schell, William, Jr. "Silver Symbiosis: Reorienting Mexican Economic
History."
Hispanic American Historical Review 81.1 (2001): 89-133.
Schiffer, Reinhold. Oriental Panorama : British Travellers in 19th Century
Turkey.
Internationale Forschungen Zur Allgemeinen Und Vergleichenden Literaturwissenschaft
; 33. Amsterdam; Atlanta, Ga.: Rodopi, 1999.
Searle, John R. The Construction of Social Reality. New York: Free Press,
1995.
Senior, Nassau William. A Journal Kept in Turkey and Greece in the Autumn
of 1857,
and the Beginning of 1858. London: Longman Brown Green Longmans and Roberts,
1859.
Shan-Si sycee.Example of China silver sycee. <http://www.charm.ru/library/sycee2.htm>
Sobrino, Jose Manuel. La Moneda Mexicana. Mexico City: Banco de Mexico,
1989.
Stride, H. "The Maria Theresa Thaler." Numismatic Chronicle
XVI (1956).
Tai, Stephen. Chopmarked Mexican Republican peso. Chopmarks on 5 Mexican
Silver
Dollars. December 18, 1999 <http://www.charm.ru/coins/misc/chopmarks.shtml>
---. Chopmarked Fernando VII real. Chopped Dollars. Feb. 28, 1998
<http://www.charm.ru/library/fsilver2.htm>
Taylor, Charles. Five Years in China: With Some Account of the Great Rebellion,
and a
Description of St. Helena. New York: Derby & Jackson, 1860.
Te-K'un. "A Brief History of Chinese Silver Currency." The Numismatist
LV (1942).
Tomlins, Christopher. "Loose Change: Making Money through History."
American
Behavioral Scientist 41.10 (1998): 1452-70.
Topik, Steven, and Allen Wells. The Second Conquest of Latin America :
Coffee,
Henequen, and Oil During the Export Boom, 1850-1930. 1st ed. Austin: Institute
of Latin American Studies University of Texas Press, 1998.
Turkish Cultural Foundation. Gold coin of Mahmud 1, 1730. Istanbul. The
Turkish
Ottoman and Seljuk Coins. <http://www.turkishculture.org/monetary/coinage.html>
Turkish Numismatic Society. The Notes of 1st. International Numismatic
Symposium.
Ed. 1993. Istambul, 1999.
Uztariz, Gerónimo de. Theorica, Y Practica De Comercio, Y De Marina,
En Diferentes
Discursos, Y Calificados Exemplares, Que, Con Especificas Providencias,
Se
Procuran Adaptar a La Monarchia Espaänola, Para Su Prompta Restauracion.
2. impression, corregida, y enmendada por el autor. ed. Madrid,: Imprenta
de A. Sanz, 1742.
Valdés Lakowsky, Vera. De Las Minas Al Mar : Historia De La Plata
Mexicana En Asia,
1565-1834. Sección De Obras De Historia. 1a ed. México,
D.F.: Fondo de Cultura Económica, 1987.
Vázquez, Josefina Zoraida, and Lorenzo Meyer. México Frente
a Estados Unidos : Un
Ensayo Histórico, 1776-2000. Sección De Obras De Historia.
4a ed. México: Fondo de Cultura Económica, 2001.
Wang, Yeh-chien. "Evolution of the Chinese Monetary System."
Conference on the
Modern Chinese Economic History. Taipei: Inst of Econ.: Academia Sinica,
1979. 425-52.
Weeks, Edwin Lord. From the Black Sea through Persia and India. New York,:
Harper &
brothers, 1896.
White, Benjamin. Silver; Its History and Romance. Detroit,: Tower Books,
1971.
Willem, John M. The United States Trade Dollar; America's Only Unwanted,
Unhonored
Coin. Library ed. New York,, 1959.
Williams, S. Wells. The Chinese Commercial Guide, Containing Treaties,
Tariffs,
Regulations, Tables, Etc., Useful in the Trade to China & Eastern
Asia; with an Appendix of Sailing Directions for Those Seas and Coasts.
5th ed. Hongkong,: A. Shortrede & co., 1863.
Wyman, Arthur C. "New Trade Dollar for Red Sea Commerce." The
Numismatist
XXXIII (1920): 138-39.
Yang, Lien-sheng. Money and Credit in China, a Short History. Harvard-Yenching
Institute Monograph Series V. 12. Cambridge,: Harvard University Press,
1952.
Zelizer, Viviana. "How People Talk About Money." American Behavioral
Scientist 41.10
(1998): 1373-173.
Notes
1 The crown passed a royal order (Ordenanza e Instrucción) dated
March 9, 1728 requiring that all coins have a "cordoncillo o laurel
al canto" to make falsification difficult (Herrera 17). If coins
were struck off center or otherwise lacked a standard milled border, it
was relatively easy to clip silver from their edges. Another method of
obtaining metal, slinging or whirling, was done by placing coins into
canvas bag and whirling them for several hours (Mossman 56). The bag was
then burned and chips of metal recovered from the ash.
2 The Republic of Mexico continued the late colonial standard of 10d 20g
even stamping the purity on the face of the coin. Both Spain and Mexico
used the medieval system of dineros and granos to measure the fineness
of their coins. Twelve dineros designated pure silver. Each dinero was
divided into 24 granos. A coin of 10 Ds. 20Gs equated to .902777 fine.
3 There is an extensive corpus of literature dealing with the Bourbon
reforms. See Lynch 3-50 for a good introduction to this subject.
4 The practice of using the king's portrait created an interesting problem.
The dies of the new king took as long as a couple of years to arrive at
Spanish American mints. In these cases the old portrait was used and the
lettering modified. This may explain why Carolus IIII was used rather
than Carolus IV.
5 The royal coat of arms on the coins consisted of a quartered shield
with castles and lions rampant in alternating cantons (Grove n1606). These
symbolized the original Castile and León of Isabel (1474-1504),
nucleus of the Spanish kingdom. In the small center shield are three fleurs-de-lis
from the house of Bourbon. At the bottom of the shield is a pomegranate
symbolizing Granada, the last Spanish territory reconquered from the Moors.
The crown is royal in keeping with the basic design from the dos mundos
coins.
6 A permanent government was not established until 1824. A decreto dated
August 1, 1823 defined the Republic's new money using José Mariano
Torreblanca's coin design (Salmeron 53). Mexican mints used this basic
coin design through the nineteenth century. The exception was the short
interlude of the French Intervention from 1866 to 1867 and a balance style
peso struck from 1869 to 1873 (Pradeau 309).
7 While eagles and snakes are native to the Americas, Asia, Africa and
Europe, cacti are only endogenous in the Americas (Crosby 4). Although
the eagle/nopal symbol first appeared on insurgent coins in 1811, the
design had been the subject of New Spain literature for centuries. See
Florescano for a recent discussion of how this image developed as a symbol
for the entire nation.
8 A notable early insurgent coin exhibited an organic strategy to show
how the nation trumped the crown. In Grove n2202 the normal bridge design
over which sat the nopal and eagle was converted into an imperial crown.
9 These circulated throughout the Middle East and parts of Africa like
Nigeria and the eastern coast of Africa-all areas with a large Muslim
population.
10 Although the mint of the Mexico City Central Bank fulfilled an order
from Saudi Arabia for thirty million 1-riyal pieces in 1949 (Pradeau 1:
287).
11 This silver rupee weighed 11.6 grams and was .985 fine.
12 This silver rupee was 180 grains troy with a fineness of .917 or 11/12
fine. This was also the weight of a tola in popular use in India (Nambudiripad
12).
13 The place in question is on the West River between Wu-chau and Pesê
(Colquhoun 1: 217).
14 After 1850, Maritime Customs managed by foreign interests accepted
Haikwan taels (Kann 153).
15 The silver that was exported from China to India was mostly in the
form of sycee silver and broken dollars (Williams 274). Indian mints priced
the sycee and coins for their silver content. Since coins were more valuable
as money in China, they were retained there.
16 The Carolus dollar (IIII variety) was called ssu-kung yin because the
Roman numeral "I" looked like the Chinese character "kung"
or "gong" (Yang 49). This would translate to "four worker
dollar."
17 Wang estimates that 134 million dollars left the country from 1827-1849
due to the opium trade (442).
18 The assayers' initials and mint name were one letter not two: for example,
Z for Zacatecas not Zs, G for Guanajuato not G with an o in it and M for
Mexico City not M with an o over it (Halliday 46).